BSDEs were first introduced by Pardoux and Peng [12]. In 1997, Peng introduced the so called $g$-expectation, a kind of nonlinear expectation, based on the solution of a BSDE driven by a Brownian motion. This expectation is called nonlinear since the linearity property of the usual (linear) expectation is violated while other properties of the (linear) expectation hold in this nonlinear case. Since then, many researchers in related fields have explored the properties of BSDEs and related $g$-expectations, see [1, 4], for example. Among the results they obtained, the comparison theorem of real-valued BSDEs turns out to be one of the cornerstone results in this theory. This comparison theorem was first established by Peng [13] in the one dimensional case and later on generalized by many authors, see [11]. It allows one to compare the solutions of two real-valued BSDEs whenever we can compare the terminal conditions and the generators. Recently the comparison theorem was extended to multidimensional case by Hu et al. [6]. An inverse problem is interesting, namely, if we can compare the solution of two BSDEs with the same terminal condition, can we compare the generators? The result of Chen [3] can be thought as the first step in solving this theorem, and then it was further developed in [2] and [8] among others.
The comparison theorem and the related converse comparison theorem are applicable to mathematical finance. These results give a necessary and sufficient condition for the wealth process to be nonnegative, and also yield several of the classical properties of utilities, see [5]. In economics and finance, the nonlinear $g$-expectation can describe the attitude of the investor, e.g., risk preference or risk aversion. In [10], the author introduces the $g$-EU theory. The validity of this theory depends on the Jensen's inequality for conditional $g$-expectation. In [2], Briand gives a counter example to show that the $g$-expectation need not satisfy Jensen's inequality for most convex functions. This raises a natural question: under what conditions will the Jensen's inequality hold? Jiang [9] and Hu [7] explored the validity of Jensen's inequality for the $g$-expectation and provide necessary and sufficient conditions for the Jensen's inequality.
BSDEs and related $g$-expectations appear in many financial problems especially in the contingent claim valuation. A more realistic case will be financial markets with jumps, where jumps are caused by natural accidents, policy interference and so on. In a market with jumps, a jump-diffusion process will more aptly describe the price of the risky asset, and hence BSDEs driven by Lévy processes are used in the contingent claim valuation. The existence and uniqueness of the solution for this kind of equation was first dealt in [1]. In [15], the author studied BSDEs with jumps and establishes several basic properties including a comparison theorem. That study also introduced a nonlinear expectation, called the $f$-expectation, related to the BSDE studied there. However, the converse comparison theorem for this kind of equation and the conditional Jensen's inequality corresponding to the nonlinear expectation are not obtained so far, to the best of our knowledge. Therfore, our first purpose in this paper is to establish a converse comparison theorem for the BSDEs driven by Lévy processes. Based on this converse comparison theorem, we will provide a necessary and sufficient condition for the Jensen's inequality to hold.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we recall the basic definitions and the notations of BSDEs driven by Lévy processes. In Section 3, we prove the converse comparison theorem for this kind of BSDEs. In Section 4, we give the sufficient and necessary condition of the Jensen's inequality for the $f$-expectation. The last section reflects on the conclusions of this work and discusses about our future work.
This section sets up the notations, terminologies, and assumptions that will be in force for the rest of this work. We fix a finite time horizon $ T < \infty $ and the natural filtration $\mathcal {F}= \{\mathcal {F}_t\}_{t \in [0, T]}$, which is generated by two mutually independent processes $\{B_t\}_{t \in [0, T]}$ and $\{N_t\}_{t \in [0, T]}$. Here, $\{B_t\}_{t \in [0, T]}$ is a d-dimensional Brownian motion, $\{N_t\}_{t \in [0, T]}$ is a Lévy process with its Poisson random measure $\mu(ds, dx)$ defined on $[0, T]\times R^*$, where $ R^*= R\setminus\{0\}$, the compensator of the Poisson random measure is $\nu (ds, dx) = \lambda (dx)ds$, and $\widetilde\mu (ds, dx)= \mu(ds, dx)-\nu (ds, dx)$ is a martingale measure for all $A \in \mathcal{B}( R^*)$, where $\lambda (A)< \infty$. Moreover, $\lambda$ is a $\sigma$-finite measure defined on $\mathcal{B}( R^*)$, such that $\int_{ R^* } {(1 \wedge x^2 )} \lambda (dx) < \infty$. We shall now introduce some basic spaces that we will be working with.
the set of $\mathcal {F}_t$-progressively measurable $R$-valued processes, where $\mathcal {P}$ denotes the $\sigma$-field of predictable sets on $[0, T] \times \Omega, $ and
where $\mathcal {L}^2 (B)$ denotes the square integrable predictable processes with respect to the Brownian filtration.
Let $\eta \in L^2(\mathcal {F}_T)$ be the terminal condition. We consider
Definition 2.1 A solution of the equation
with parameters $(f, \eta)$ is a triple of processes $(Y_t, Z_t, U_t) \in {\mathcal {S}}^2 \times {\mathcal {L}}^2 (W) \times {\mathcal {L}}^2 (\widetilde\mu )$ satisfying that equation for any $t \in [0, T].$
Next we consider the existence and uniqueness of the solution.
Lemma 2.2(see [15]) There exists a unique solution for equation (2.1) in ${\mathcal {S}}^2 \times {\mathcal {L}}^2 (W) \times {\mathcal {L}}^2 (\widetilde\mu )$ provided the generator $f$ satisfies the following conditions:
(ⅰ) $E\left[\int_0^T {\left| {f(s, 0, 0, 0)} \right|^2 ds} \right] < \infty$;
(ⅱ) $f$ is Lipschitz continuous $w.r.t \ y, z$ with the Lipschitz constant $K$;
(ⅲ) there exist constants $-1 < C_1 \leq 0$ and $C_2 \geq 0$ such that for any
we have
where $ \gamma _t^{y, z, u, u'}: \ \ \Omega \times [0, T] \times R^* \rightarrow R $ is ${\mathcal {P}} \times {\mathcal{B}(R^*)}$-measurable and satisfies
The last condition (ⅲ) implies that $f$ is Lipschitz continuous in $u$, with Lipschitz constant denoted by $A$, and
We shall now recall a comparison theorem for BSDE driven by a Lévy process, see [15]. Let $(Y^i, Z^i, U^i)$ $(i=1, 2)$ be two solutions of our equation (2.1) associated respectively with $(\eta^1, f^1)$ and $(\eta^2, f^2).$ Then, we have the following
Theorem 2.3(see [15]) Assume that the conditions in Lemma 2.2 are fulfilled for $\eta^1$, $\eta^2$, $f^1$ and $f^2.$ If $\eta^1\leq \eta^2$ a.s., and $f^1(t, Y_t^1, Z_t^1, U_t^1)\leq f^2(t, Y_t^1, Z_t^1, U_t^1)$, $dt\times dP$ a.e., then $Y_t^1\leq Y_t^2$ for $t\in [0, T]$ a.s.
Definition 2.4 Consider a BSDE driven by a Lévy process with generator $f$, satisfying
(ⅰ) $f(s, y, 0, 0)=0, \forall y \in R$;
(ⅱ) $f$ is Lipschitz continuous in $y, z $;
(ⅲ) $f$ satisfies the third condition in Lemma 2.2.
For any $\eta$ fixed in $ \mathcal {L} ^2(\Omega, \mathcal {F}_T, P)$, we denote the unique solution of the related BSDE by $(Y^{\eta, f, T}_t, Z^{\eta, f, T}_t, U^{\eta, f, T}_t)$. Let $ \varepsilon_f (\eta ) = Y_0^{\eta, f, T}$ denote the initial value of the solution. Then $ \varepsilon_f$ is a non-linear expectation called $f$-expectation.
Lemma 2.5 Let, for any $\xi\in L^2(\Omega, \mathcal {F}_T, P)$, $f$ satisfies the conditions in Definition 2.4. Then there exists a unique random variable $\eta \in L^2(\Omega, \mathcal {F}_T, P)$, such that
This $\eta$ ic called the conditional $f$-expectation of $\xi$ and is denoted by $ \varepsilon_f[\xi \mid \mathcal {F}_t]$. Moreover, $ \varepsilon_f[\xi \mid \mathcal {F}_t]=Y^{\xi, f, T}_t$ is the solution of equation (2.1) at time $t$.
In this section, we present one of the main result of this paper, namely, the converse comparison theorem for the solutions of BSDEs driven by Lévy processes.
Suppose the triple $(Y, Z, U)$ is the solution of the BSDE (2.1) and the generator $f$ satisfies the following
Assumption 3.1 For all $ (y, p, q)$, almost all sample paths $t \to f(t, y, p, q)$ are continuous.
To establish our converse comparison theorem, we need the following two lemmas.
Lemma 3.2 Let $(Y, Z, U)$ be the solution of BSDE (2.1). We then have
where $C$ is a positive constant and $\beta=2K+4K^2$, (recall that $K$ is the Lipschitz constant of $f$ with respect to $y$ and $z$).
Proof For any constant $\beta$, it follows from Ito's formula that
Also,
Taking $\beta=4K^2+2K$, we see from (3.1) and (3.2), that
In (3.3), let $s=t$ and take the conditional expectation to get
It follows from equation (3.1) that
The following estimate holds by equation (3.2).
Therefore
and consequently
By the Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality,
Then, by estimates (3.4) and (3.5), we have
For any fixed $p, q\in R$, put
Lemma 3.3 Supposing $E[\sup_{0\leq t\leq T}|f(t, 0, 0, 0)|^2]$ is finite, we have
Proof For any fixed $(t, y, p, q)$ and $t\leq s \leq t+\dfrac{1}{n}$, put
Then $d{ \widetilde{^nY_s}}=d{^nY_s}-pd(B_{s}-B_t)-qd\int_t^{s}\int_{R^*} 1\wedge |x| \widetilde{\mu}(du, dx)$, that is
By Lemma 3.2 and $E[\sup_{0\leq t\leq T}|f(t, 0, 0, 0)|^2]$ is finite, we have the following estimation
where $C_{y, p, q}$ is a constant depending on $y, p$ and $q$.
Since
where
we then get
Now, by inequality (3.6),
Let
Then
and
Obviously $ I\leq K\dfrac{p^2}{2}\dfrac{1}{n^2}+K\dfrac{q^2}{2}\dfrac{1}{n}+(p^2+q^2)\dfrac{1}{n}\longrightarrow 0. $ By Assumption 3.1, we easily see $II\rightarrow 0$, and hence the result holds.
Now, here is our converse comparison theorem.
Theorem 3.4 Let $f_1(t, y, p, q)$ and $f_2(t, y, p, q)$ satisfy the conditions in Lemma 2.2 and in Definition 2.4. $\forall \eta \in L^2(\mathcal {F}_T)$, denote $Y_t^1(\eta)=Y_t^{\eta, f_1, T}$, $Y_t^2(\eta)=Y_t^{\eta, f_2, T}$. If $\forall t\in [0, T]$, we have $Y_t^1(\eta)\leq Y_t^2(\eta)$, $P-$a.s., then $\forall(t, y, p, q)$, $f_1(t, y, p, q)\leq f_2(t, y, p, q)$ holds $P-$a.s..
Proof For any fixed $(t, y, p, q)$, define
By Lemma 3.3, we know $ n(Y_t^i(\eta_n)-y)\longrightarrow f_i(t, y, p, q), i=1, 2 $ in $L^2$ sense.
On the other hand, $ n(Y_t^1(\eta_n)-y)\leq n(Y_t^2(\eta_n)-y), $ so
By Assumptions 3.1, $\forall(t, y, p, q)$, $f_1(t, y, p, q)\leq f_2(t, y, p, q)$ holds $P-$a.s..
In this section, we give a necessary and sufficient condition for the Jensen's inequality to hold under the $f$-expectation that has been defined in Section 2. Indeed, we appeal to the Converse Comparison Theorem to prove this basic inequality.
Theorem 4.1 Suppose $f$ satisfies the conditions in Lemma 2.2, Definition 2.4, and Assumption 3.1. Then the following statements are equivalent
(1) $P-$a.s $f$ dose not depend on $y$, and for $\forall\lambda \in R$ and $(t, p, q)$,
(2) the conditional Jensen's inequality holds, that is, $\forall \eta\in L^2(\mathcal {F}_T)$ and a convex function $\psi$ defined on $R$, the following inequality holds $ \varepsilon_f[\psi(\eta)\mid \mathcal {F}_t]\geq \psi(\varepsilon_f[\eta\mid \mathcal {F}_t]), P-{\rm a.s.}. $
Proof $(1)\Longrightarrow (2)$ Let $\varphi(x)=\lambda x+u$, $\lambda\neq0$. Let $(Y, Z, U)$ denote the solution of the following BSDE
and $(Y', Z', U')$ the solution of the following BSDE
where $f'(t, p, q)=\lambda f(t, \frac{p}{\lambda}, \frac{q}{\lambda})$. Obviously, $ Y'_t=\lambda Y_t+u, Z'=\lambda Z, U'=\lambda U $ and
For $P-$a.s., $f(t, p, q)\geq f'(t, p, q)$, by comparison Theorem 2.3, we have
and $ \varepsilon_{f'}[\varphi(\eta)\mid \mathcal {F}_t]=Y'_t=\lambda Y_t+u=\lambda\varepsilon_f[\eta\mid \mathcal {F}_t]+u=\varphi[\varepsilon_f(\eta\mid \mathcal {F}_t)]. $ For any convex function $\psi$, there exists a countable set $D$ on $R^2$ such that
For any $(\lambda, u)\in D$,
For $D$ is a countable set,
$(2)\Longrightarrow (1)$ Let $(Y, Z, U)$ be the solution of the following BSDE:
and $(Y', Z', U')$ be the solution of the following BSDE
where $f'(t, y, p, q)=\lambda f(t, \dfrac{y-u}{\lambda}, \frac{p}{\lambda}, \frac{q}{\lambda})$, and $\varphi(x)=\lambda x+u$ is a convex function.
As above, we have
By Theorem 3.4, $\forall (t, y, p, q)$, we have $f(t, y, p, q)\geq f'(t, y, p, q)$, $P-$a.s., that is
Let $\lambda=1$. Then, $f(t, y+u, p, q)\geq f(t, y, p, q)$, that means $f$ dose not depend on $y$, and we can easily get that $f(t, \lambda p, \lambda q)\geq \lambda f(t, p, q)$.
BSDEs driven by Lévy processes are widely used in mathematical finance, especially in the contingent claim evaluation in incomplete market. In this paper, we give the converse comparison theorem for the BSDEs driven by Lévy processes. The sufficient and necessary condition is obtained via the converse comparison theorem. These two results are the generalization of the corresponding results for BSDEs driven by Brownian motion, and they can be used in contingent claim evaluation, which has been mentioned in Section 1. There are many elementary problems to be solved for the $f$-expectation, such as up-crossing inequality etc.