Bequest motives are long recognized as potentially important determinants of saving patterns. However, there is very little work directed at describing how they affect optimal consumption patterns.
In the paper[1], Jousten introduced a linear bequest motive into a standard life-cycle model to inquires bequests impact on annuity valuation. Recently, Dalgaard and Jensen integrated the bequest motives into classical Diamond model to study their effect on the process of capital accumulation and showed that if the bequest motive dominates, the scale effect is positive. If the life-cycle motive dominates, the scale effect is ambiguous and may even be negative[2].
In this paper, we set up a life-cycle model with bequest motives by integrating the utility function of bequest into the life-cycle model provided by Futagami and Nakajima[3] and the method of dynamic optimization similar to[4]. It is proved the model has optimal consumption path and bequest and the individual consumes more and leaves more bequest when individual's income increased or gets more heritage.
The effects of four types of concrete bequest function on the individual's consumption and saving behaviour is discussed. In the cases of the logarithmic bequest motives and linear bequest motives, the closed-form expression of the individual's consumption and bequest are given. For the homothetic bequest motives and threshold bequest motives, we obtain that the individual has optimal consumption stream and bequest to maximize lifetime utility. It is proved that the greater the strength of the bequest motive, the greater the savings rate and bequest in the last three bequest motives and the individual's consumption increases, savings decreases with the increase of the threshold for the threshold bequest motives.
Denote the consumption and asset of individuals who born at time 0 by $c(t), a(t)$ at time $t$. The individual retires at time $R$ and his finite lifespan is $\Omega>R$. Individuals derive satisfaction from their consumption and have bequest motives. We assume that individuals start their lives with assets (from heritage) and end up with bequest and have no debt, i.e.,
Assume that the individual provides inelastically a labor and earns the wage $w(t)$ when he works and has no income when he retires, i.e., the individual's income is given by
Therefore the individual budget constraint hence writes
where the interest rate $r$ is a constant.
Assume that the utility functions of individual from consumption and bequest is given by
and $\phi(a(\Omega), \phi'(\cdot)>0, \phi''(\cdot)\leq 0$. Then the individual's optimization problem is to maximize
subject to(2.1)-(2.3), where $\rho$ stands for the rate of time preference.
The Hamiltonian for the problem is to solve the optimization problem is
The first order conditions and transversality condition are
From(3.4) and(3.3), $\ln\lambda(t)=-\rho+\ln u'(c(t))$ and $\frac{\dot c}{c}=\sigma(r-\rho)$. So we have
By(3.2), we have
and
From the transversality condition(3.5), we obtain
since $\lambda(t)=\lambda(0)e^{-rt}$. By(3.4), $u'(c)=c^{-\frac{1}{\sigma}}=\lambda(t)e^{\rho t}$, we have $c^{-\frac{1}{\sigma}}(0)=\lambda(0)$, i.e.,
Let
and $g(x)=b-g_1(x)$, then we have following lemma.
Lemma 3.1 If $g_1(0)<b$, then the function $g(x)$ has a unique zero $x_1$ on the interval $[0, +\infty)$ and there exists unique initial consumption $c(0)$ and bequest $a(\Omega)$ such the equation(3.8) and(3.10) hold.
Proof Since
and $\lim\limits_{x\to +\infty}g_1(x)=+\infty$, there exists a unique $x_1$ such that $g_1(x_1)=b$. Therefore, the function $g(x)$ has a unique zero on the interval $[0, +\infty)$. This completes the proof of Lemma 3.1.
By Lemma 3.1, we obtain
Theorem 3.1 Under the condition of Lemma 3.1, the individual has optimal consumption path and bequest in his life cycle and the consumption path is given by (3.6), the initial consumption is determined by equation (3.8) and (3.10).
From the proof of Lemma 3.1, we see that the zero $x_1$ increases when $b$ become large. So from (3.8), we have following theorem.
Theorem 3.2 When individual get more heritage $a(0)$ or income($\displaystyle\int_0^Re^{-rt}w(t)dt$) from his work period, then he will consume more and leave more bequest under the condition of Lemma 3.1.
In this section, the utility of individual from consumption is assumed to be logarithmic, i.e., $u(c)=\ln c$ and the effects of four specified bequest motives on the individual's consumption and saving behaviour are discussed.
In this subsection, we assume that the utility functions of individuals from the bequest is logarithmical, i.e., $\phi[a(\Omega)]=\ln a(\Omega)$. From
$g_1(0)=0$ and the condition of Lemma 3.1 holds. Hence we have following theorem.
Theorem 4.1 Under logarithmic bequest motives, the individual's consumption path and bequest and are given by
Proof It is only to prove the last part. When $\sigma=1$, from (3.10), $c(0)=e^{-r\Omega}a(\Omega)$. Substitute it into (3.8), we have $c(0)=\frac{\displaystyle\int_0^R e^{-rt}w(t)dt+a(0)}{\displaystyle\int_0^\Omega e^{-\rho t}dt+1}$ and $a(\Omega)=\frac{\displaystyle\int_0^R e^{-rt}w(t)dt+a(0)}{\displaystyle\int_0^\Omega e^{-\rho t}dt+1}e^{r\Omega}.$ This completes the proof of Theorem 4.1.
In this subsection, we consider the case of linear bequest. With linear bequest motives, preferences over consumption and bequests are quasilinear and bequests are luxury goods. People with linear bequest motives leave bequests only if they have more than enough wealth to purchase their desired consumption stream. They leave any wealth in excess if this amount as bequests. Linear bequest motives are sometimes used to approximate altruistic bequest motives[4] which arise from concern about the welfare of one's heirs, and are sometimes used to describe "joy-of-giving" bequest motives[5], which arise from enjoying giving for its own sake. Most altruists should have approximately linear bequest motives because bequests are typically small relative to recipients' total wealth. A linear bequest motive matches Hurd and Smith's estimates of the increase in anticipated bequests during the 1990s boom in asset markets almost perfectly[6].
The utility function of linear bequest motives is given by
and from the transversality condition (3.5),
So from $\theta_1=\lambda(0)e^{-r\Omega}$ and $c(0)=\frac{1}{\lambda(0)}$, we have
By(3.8), we have
and following theorems.
Theorem 4.2 Under the linear bequest motives, the optimal consumption path and bequest are given by (4.3) and (4.4).
Theorem 4.3 The greater the strength of the bequest motive $\theta_1$, the greater the savings rate and bequest.
Proof By(4.3) and (4.4), we have
So the theorem holds.
With this bequest motive, preferences over consumption and bequests are homothetic: people with twice as much wealth consume twice as much and leave bequests that are twice as large. This bequest motive is inconsistent with the evidence that bequests are luxury goods[7]. The utility function of homothetic bequest motives is given by
The condition of Lemma 3.1 satisfies. So from Theorem 3.1, we have following theorem.
Theorem 4.4 Under the homothetic bequest motives bequest, the individual has optimal consumption stream and bequest to maximize lifetime utility.
Theorem 4.5 The stronger the bequest motive, the greater bequest and the saving rate.
Proof Let
then from the proof of Lemma 3.1, there exists a unique $x_1>0$ such that $G(x_1, \theta_1)=0$ for any given $\theta_1>0$. Since
This implies that $x_1$ increases when $\theta_1$ increases, i.e., the bequest $a(\Omega)$ increases. By (3.8), the initial consumption $c(0)$ decreases with $\theta_1$ increasing as well as the consumption all life. This completes the proof of the theorem.
Threshold bequest motives used by De Nardi[7-8] are similar to linear bequest motives in that bequest are luxury goods. But they are unlike linear bequest motives in that the marginal utility of bequests decreases in the size of the bequest, which implies that people are risk averse over bequests. $\theta_2$ determines the threshold wealth level below which an individual will consume all her wealth leaves no bequest. Richer individuals divide their wealth above the threshold between consumption and bequests in a fixed proportion. The larger is $\theta_2$, the higher is the threshold, and so the greater the extent to which bequests are luxury goods.
The utility function of threshold bequest motives is given by
and $\phi'(x)=\theta_1(\theta_2+x)^{-\eta}, \phi''(x)=-\eta\theta_1(\theta_2)x^{-\eta-1}<0$,
So from Theorem 3.1, we have following theorem.
Theorem 4.6 If $\frac{e^{-r\Omega}\theta_2^\eta}{\theta_1}<b$, the individual has optimal consumption stream and bequest to maximize lifetime utility under the threshold bequest motives bequest.
Theorem 4.7 The stronger the bequest motive, the greater bequest and the saving rate.
This implies that $x_1$ increases when $\theta_1$ increasing, i.e., the bequest increases. By (3.8), the initial consumption $c(0)$ decreases with $\theta_1$ increasing as well as the consumption all life. This completes the proof of the theorem.
Theorem 4.8 With the increase of the threshold $\theta_2$, consumption will increase, the savings will decrease.
then from the proof of Lemma 3.1, there exists a unique $x_1>0$ such that $G(x_1, \theta_1)=0$ for any given $\theta_2>0$.
Since
This implies that $x_1$ decrease when $\theta_2$ increases, i.e., the bequest $a(\Omega)$ decreases. By (3.8), the initial consumption $c(0)$ increases as well as the consumption all life. This completes the proof of the theorem.
In this paper, the conditions of the initial consumption and bequest needed to satisfy is first given by the first order conditions to solve the individual all life utility maximization problem. From (3.8), we first see that the individual consumes less and saving more with bequest motives (with $a(\Omega)>0$) than that without bequest motives ($a(\Omega)=0$). Then we obtain that the individual consumes more and leaves more bequest when individual's income increased or gets more heritage. Under a given condition, it is proved that there exists positive bequest when the bequest has utility for the individual and the individual chooses a optimal consumption path to maximize his all life utility. This is the reason why the Asian countries such as China has high saving rate[9-11].
The effects of four specified bequest motives function on the individual's consumption and saving behaviours are discussed. For the cases of the logarithmic bequest motives and linear bequest motives, the initial consumption and bequests can be solved by the first order conditions. So the optimal consumption path and asset path has a closed-form expression. The effects of the strength of bequest motives on individual's consumption and saving behaviours are also inquired. It is proved that the greater the strength of the bequest motive, the greater the savings rate and bequest in the last three bequest motives and the individual's consumption increases, savings decreases with the increase of the threshold for the threshold bequest motives which implies that the bequest are luxury goods.