Due to the wide applications in many aspects of applied mathematics, properties of homogeneous functions have been studied by many authors, see, for instance, [1-5]. However, it is worth mentioning that there are many homogeneous functions which are not differentiable, and there exist few studies of nonsmooth homogeneous optimization problems defined by positively homogeneous and locally Lipschitzian functions in real Banach spaces.
In the work [1], the homogeneous optimization problems were extended to nonsmooth functions, but there is still much work left to do. Meantime, we note that some results in section 4 there require the assumption $\sum\limits_{i=1}^{m}\bar{\lambda}_{i}\frac{(p-q_{i})q_{i}b_{i}}{p}\neq0, \, \, {\rm i.e.}, \, \, p\neq q_{i}$, for some $i\in\{i\in M:\bar{\lambda}_{i}\neq0\}$. In order to avoid the weakness mentioned above, inspired by the technique used in [2], we will give a modification of the model there.
In this paper, by using the generalized Euler identity for Clarke's subdifferential, we obtain a sufficient condition for an optimal solution of (HOP) to be a KKT point:
Moreover, the relationship between (HOP) and its embedding problem $(\widehat{\mathrm{HOP}})$ is also considered:
where the functions involved in (HOP) and $(\widehat{\mathrm{HOP}})$ are all positively homogeneous.
The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we give some preliminaries and definitions. In section 3, we give a sufficient condition for an optimal solution of the nonsmooth homogeneous optimization problem (HOP) to be a KKT point. In section 4, the one-to-one correspondence of the KKT points the optimal solutions of (HOP) and $(\widehat{\mathrm{HOP}})$ is established.
Let $X$ be a real Banach space with the topological dual $X^{*}$, $\langle., .\rangle$ be the duality paring between $X$ and $X^{*}$ and $\Omega$ be a closed cone of $X$. We now introduce the nonsmooth homogeneous optimization problem:
where $f, \, g_{i}:X\rightarrow R\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, m)$ are positively homogeneous functions with degree $p, \, q_{i}\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, m)$, respectively, and each $b_{i}\in R\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, m)$.
We denote by $K$ the set of feasible solutions of (HOP), i.e.,
The following definitions and lemmas will be useful in the next two sections.
Definition2.1(see [6]) A function $f:X\rightarrow R$ is said to be Lipschitzian of rank $L$ near a given point $x\in X$, if there exists some $\delta>0$ such that
We say that $f:X\rightarrow R$ is locally Lipschitzian on $X$ if it is Lipschitzian near any point of $X$.
Definition2.2(see [6]) Let $f:X\rightarrow R$ be locally Lipschitzian on $X$. The generalized directional derivative of $f$ at $x$ in the direction $v$, denoted by $f^{\circ}(x;v)$, is defined as follows:
where $y$ is a vector in $X$ and $t$ is a positive scalar.
We call the set
the Clarke's subdifferential of $f$ at $x$.
It is easy to verify that
Lemma2.1(see [6]) Let $f_{i}\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, n)$ be Lipschitzian near $x$, and let $\lambda_{i}\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, n)$ be scalars. Then $f:=\sum\limits_{i=1}^{n}\lambda_{i}f_{i}$ is Lipschitzian near $x$, and we have
Definition2.3(see [7]) Let $X$ be a real Banach space, and $C$ be a nonempty subset of $X$. The Clarke tangent cone to $C$ at $x\in C$ is defined by
where $d_{C}(x)=\inf\limits_{z\in C}\|z-x\|$, and the Clarke normal cone to $C$ at $x\in C$ is defined by
Now we give the definition of invexity which is taken from [8].
Definition2.4 A function $f:\Omega\rightarrow R$ is said to be nonsmooth invex at $\bar{x}\in \Omega$, if for any $x\in \Omega$ and $\xi\in\partial f(\bar{x})$, there exists $\eta(x, \bar{x})\in T_{\Omega}(\bar{x})$ such that
Let $g=(g_{1}, g_{2}, \cdots, g_{m})$ be a vector-valued function from $\Omega$ to $R^{m}$, then $g$ is said to be nonsmooth invex at $x\in \Omega$, if each $g_{i}\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, m)$ is nonsmooth invex at $x\in \Omega$.
Recall that a function $f:X\rightarrow R$ is said to be positively homogeneous with degree $p\, (p>0)$ provided that the equality $f(\lambda x)=\lambda^{p}f(x)$ holds for any $x\in X$ and $\lambda>0$.
As is well known, when a $p$-homogeneous function $\varphi:R^{n}\rightarrow R$ is differentiable, there is an identity, the so-called Euler formula,
The above formula was extended to nonsmooth homogeneous and locally Lipschitzian function defined on a real Banach space as follows.
Lemma2.2(see [9]) Let $X$ be a real Banach space and $f:X\rightarrow R$ be a $p$-positively homogeneous $(p>0)$ and locally Lipschitzian function. Then, for each $x\in X$ and $\xi\in \partial f(x)$, the following identity holds:
We denote it simply as the following formula:
Definition2.5 $\bar{x}\in K$ is said to be an optimal solution or a global minimum of (HOP) if $f(\bar{x})\leqslant f(x), $ for all $x\in K$, or equivalently, there exists no $x\in K$ such that $f(x)<f(\bar{x}).$
Definition2.6 $\bar{x}\in K$ is said to be a KKT (Karash-Kuhn-Tucker) point of (HOP), if there exists a L-KKT(Lagrange-KKT) multiplier $\bar{\lambda}=(\bar{\lambda}_{1}, \bar{\lambda}_{2}, \cdots, \bar{\lambda}_{m})\in R_{+}^{m}$ such that
Definition2.7 The problem (HOP) is said to satisfy the Slater constraint qualification, if there exists $\tilde{x}\in \Omega$ such that $g_{i}(\tilde{x})-b_{i}<0, \, \, i=1, 2, \cdots, m$.
For notational convenience, we denote $M=\{i:i=1, 2, \cdots, m\}$ in the next two sections.
In this section, we first give a fine result about the KKT points under appropriate assumptions.
Theorem3.1 Let $f$, $g_{i}\, (i\in M)$ be locally Lipschitzian and positively homogeneous functions with degree $p$, $q_{i}\, (i\in M)$, respectively. If $\bar{x}\in K$ is a KKT point of (HOP), then
where $\bar{\lambda}=(\bar{\lambda}_{1}, \bar{\lambda}_{2}, \cdots, \bar{\lambda}_{m})\in R_{+}^{m}$ is a L-KKT multiplier associated with $\bar{x}$.
Proof Let $\bar{x}\in K$ be a KKT point of (HOP) with associated L-KKT multiplier $\bar{\lambda}=(\bar{\lambda}_{1}, \bar{\lambda}_{2}, \cdots, \bar{\lambda}_{m})\in R_{+}^{m}$. It follows from (2.2) that there exist $\xi\in\partial f(\bar{x})$ and $\zeta_{i}\in \partial g_{i}(\bar{x})\, (i\in M)$ such that
By the homogeneity of $f$ and the generalized Euler identity (2.1), we have
Hence, $f(\bar{x})=-\sum\limits_{i=1}^{m}\bar{\lambda}_{i}\frac{q_{i}}{p}b_{i}.$ This completes the proof.
Now, we are ready to prove that an optimal solution of (HOP) is necessarily a KKT point under appropriate conditions.
For notational convenience, we denote $I=\{i\in M:\lambda_{i}\neq0\}$, where $\lambda_{i}\, (i\in M)$ is a L-KKT multiplier associated with some fixed KKT point $\bar{x}$.
Theorem3.2 Suppose that
(1) $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i\in M)$ are all Lipschitzian near $\bar{x}\in \Omega$;
(2) $f$ and $g_{i}\, \, (i\in I)$ are nonsmooth invex at $\bar{x}\in \Omega$ with respect to same $\eta\in T_{\Omega}(\bar{x})$;
(3) $f$ and $g_{i}\, \, (i\in I)$ are positively homogeneous with degree $p$, $q_{i}\, (i\in I), $respectively;
(4) the Slater constraint qualification is satisfied.
If $\bar{x}$ is an optimal solution of (HOP), then $\bar{x}$ is a KKT point of (HOP) and there exists $\bar{\lambda}=(\bar{\lambda}_{1}, \bar{\lambda}_{2}, \cdots, \bar{\lambda}_{m})\in R_{+}^{m}$ such that
Proof Since $\bar{x}$ is an optimal solution of (HOP), we have by [7, Theorem6.1.1], there exist $\tau\in R_{+}$, $\lambda=(\lambda_{1}, \cdots, \lambda_{m})\in R_{+}^{m}$, $(\tau, \lambda)\neq0$, such that
By (3.2), there exist $\xi\in \partial f(\bar{x})$, $\zeta_{i}\in\partial g_{i}(\bar{x})\, (i\in M)$ such that
or equivalently
Using the nonsmooth invexity property of $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i\in I)$ at $\bar{x}\in \Omega$, we have, for any $x\in \Omega$ and a suitable vector $\eta\in T_{\Omega}(\bar{x})$,
Now we claim $\tau\neq0$. In fact, if possible $\tau=0$, then $\lambda=(\lambda_{1}, \lambda_{2}, \cdots, \lambda_{m})\neq0$, by (3.3) and (3.4),
By Slater constraint qualification, there exists $\tilde{x}\in \Omega$ such that
which is a contradiction to (3.5).
According to (3.4) and $\tau\neq0$, we obtain
where $\bar{\lambda}_{i}=\frac{\lambda_{i}}{\tau}\geqslant0, \, \, i\in M$.
So $\bar{x}$ is a minimum point of the following problem
which gives that
In view of (3.3) and (3.6), $\bar{x}$ is necessarily a KKT point of (HOP). And by Theorem 3.1, we have
Let $X=R^{n}$, then we have the following result.
Corollary3.1 Suppose that
(1) $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i\in M)$ are all continuously differentiable near $\bar{x}\in \Omega$;
(2) $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i\in I)$ are all convex on $\Omega$;
(3) $f$ and $g_{i}\, \, (i\in I)$ are positively homogeneous with degree $p$, $q_{i}\, (i\in I), $ respectively;
Remark3.1 It is worth mentioning that our results above can be applied in mathematical Finance theory. Assume that there are only n kinds of risk assets in the market, denoted by $X_{1}, X_{2}, \cdots, X_{n}$, and there are only two moments, today (denoted by 0) and future (denoted by 1). The one-period returns of the risk assets, $R_{1}, R_{2}, \cdots, R_{n}$, are all random variable. $R=(R_{1}, R_{2}, \cdots, R_{n})$ is a vector, $\omega=(\omega_{1}, \omega_{2}, \cdots, \omega_{n})^{T}$, $\sum\limits_{i=1}^{n}\omega_{i}=1$, is a portfolio, where $\omega_{i}$ is the investment ratio on $X_{i}\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, n)$. $E(R)=\big(E(R_{1}), E(R_{2}), \cdots, E(R_{n})\big)^{T}$ is a vector, where $E(R_{i})$ is the expected return on $X_{i}\, (i=1, 2, \cdots, n)$. As is well known, Markowitz's Mean-Variance model can be written as follows (for more details, see [10] or [11]):
where $l=(1, 1, \cdots, 1)^{T}$ is a $\mathit{n}$-dimensional vector, each component of which is 1, $\Sigma$ is a reversible variance-covariance matrix. The constraint qualification (3.8), (3.9) shows that $\omega$ is a portfolio and the expected return of the portfolio is a constant $\bar{\mu}$.
It is obvious that the model (3.7) is a special homogeneous optimization problem. For this problem, we take the functions $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i=1, 2)$ in the Theorem 3.2 as follows:
and
Since the feasible set of the problem is a bounded closed set in $R^{n}$ for each fixed $\bar{\mu}$, then the problem (3.7) has an optimal solution $\bar{\omega}$, and it is not difficult to verify that the conditions of Corollary 3.1 are satisfied. Therefore
Let
then it is not difficult to obtain that
where
Therefore
In [1], the homogeneous optimization problem was extended to nonsmooth homogeneous functions, but there exist weak points in the model there. In fact, some results in section 4 there require the assumption $\sum\limits_{i=1}^{m}\bar{\lambda}_{i}\frac{(p-q_{i})q_{i}b_{i}}{p}\neq0, \, \, {\rm i.e.}, \, \, p\neq q_{i}$, for some $i\in\{i\in M:\bar{\lambda}_{i}\neq0\}$.
Let $0<\alpha\leqslant1$ be a fixed positive scalar. In order to avoid the weakness mentioned above, following the idea of Ref. [2], we consider here a modification of $(\widehat{\mathrm{HOP}})$ as follows (we still denote it as $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$ for convenience):
where $f, \, \, g_{i}: X\rightarrow R\, (i\in M)$ are positively homogeneous functions with degree $p$, $q_{i}\, (i\in M)$, respectively, and $b_{i}\in R\, (i\in M)$.
We denote by $H$ the set of feasible solutions of $(\widehat{\mathrm{HOP}})$, i.e.,
Definition4.1 A point $(\bar{x}, \bar{u})\in H$ is said to be a KKT point of $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$ if there exists a L-KKT multiplier $(\bar{\lambda}, \bar{\mu})\in R_{+}^{m}\times R_{+}$ such that
Next, we are ready to prove that the KKT points of (HOP) have a one to one correspondence to the KKT points of $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$.
Theorem4.1 Let X be a real Banach space and $\Omega$ be a closed cone of $X$. Assume that $f: \Omega\rightarrow R$ is a locally Lipschitzian and positively homogeneous function with degree $p$, and $g_{i}: \Omega \rightarrow R\, (i\in M)$ are locally Lipschitzian and positively homogeneous functions with degree $q_{i}\, (i\in M)$. Then
(ⅰ) If $\bar{x}\in \Omega$ is a KKT point of (HOP) with associated L-KKT multiplier $\bar{\lambda}\in R_{+}^{m}$, then $(\bar{x}, 1-\alpha)$ is a KKT point of $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$ with associated L-KKT multiplier $(\bar{\lambda}, 0)\in R_{+}^{m}\times R_{+}$.
(ⅱ) If $(\bar{x}, \bar{u})\in H$ is a KKT point of $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$ with associated L-KKT multiplier $(\bar{\lambda}, \bar{\mu})\in R_{+}^{m}\times R_{+}$, and suppose further that
then $\bar{u}=1-\alpha, \, \, \bar{\mu}=0$; hence, $\bar{x}$ is a KKT point of (HOP) and $\bar{\lambda}\in R_{+}^{m}$ is a L-KKT multiplier associated with $\bar{x}$.
Proof (ⅰ) Let $\bar{x}\in \Omega$ be a KKT point with associated L-KKT multiplier
It follows from (2.2) that there exist $\xi\in\partial f(\bar{x})$ and $\zeta_{i}\in\partial g_{i}(\bar{x})$ such that
By the generalized Euler identity (2.1), the above equality can be written as
Dividing both sides of the above equality by $p\, (>0)$, we have
Considering $\bar{\lambda}_{i}[g_{i}(\bar{x})-b_{i}]=0(i\in M)$, we obtain
Take $\bar{u}=1-\alpha, \, \bar{\mu}=0$, then (4.1)-(4.3) follow from (2.2), (2.3), (4.7), directly. Moreover, $\bar{u}\bar{\mu}=0$ holds trivially, since $\bar{\mu}=0$.
(ⅱ) Suppose that $(\bar{x}, \bar{u}), \, (\bar{\lambda}, \bar{\mu})$ satisfies the condition (4.1)-(4.4). Now we show that $\bar{x}, \, \bar{\lambda}$ satisfies (2.2) and (2.3). Since $\bar{u}+\alpha>0$, (4.1) reduces to
Thus, (2.2) is satisfied. And, there exist $\xi\in \partial f(\bar{x})$, $\zeta_{i}\in \partial g_{i}(\bar{x})\, (i\in M)$ such that
Therefore,
i.e.,
From the above equality and (4.2), we have
and it follows from (4.3) that
From (4.8) and (4.9), we see that
Since the condition (4.5) is satisfied, it gives that
If $ \bar{\mu}>0$, then it follows from (4.10) that $\bar{u}>1-\alpha\geqslant0$, which contradicts (4.4). So, $\bar{\mu}=0$, $\bar{u}=1-\alpha$. Then (2.3) holds directly from (4.3), which completes the proof.
In particular, setting $\alpha=1$, we have the following results.
Corollary4.1 Let $X$, $\Omega$, $f$ and $g_{i}(i\in M)$ be given as in Theorem 4.1, then
(ⅰ) If $\bar{x}\in \Omega$ is a KKT point of (HOP) with associated L-KKT multiplier $\bar{\lambda}\in R_{+}^{m}$, then $(\bar{x}, 0)$ is a KKT point of $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$ with associated L-KKT multiplier $(\bar{\lambda}, 0)\in R_{+}^{m}\times R_{+}$.
(ⅱ) If $(\bar{x}, \bar{u})\in H$ is KKT point of $\widehat{(\mathrm{HOP})}$ with associated L-KKT multiplier $(\bar{\lambda}, \bar{\mu})\in R_{+}^{m}\times R_{+}$, and suppose further that
then $\bar{u}=0, \, \, \bar{\mu}=0$; hence, $\bar{x}$ is a KKT point of (HOP) and $\bar{\lambda}\in R_{+}^{m}$ is a L-KKT multiplier associated with $\bar{x}$.
Remark4.1 Problems similar to that of Theorem 4.1 are considered in [2] under the condition that all homogeneous function are differentiable on $\Omega\subset R^{n}$. When a function $\varphi: \Omega\rightarrow R^{n}$ is differentiable, the Clarke's subdifferential $\partial\varphi(x)$ becomes a singleton at any point $x\in\Omega$, and $\partial\varphi(x)=\{\nabla\varphi(x)\}$. So Theorem 4.1 is a generalization of [2, Theorem 2.3].
Moreover, based on the above results, the next theorem shows the one-to-one correspondence of the optimal solutions of (HOP) and $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$.
Theorem4.2 Let $X$, $\Omega$, $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i\in M)$ be given as in Theorem 4.1. Assume that the condition
is satisfied and $b_{i}>0\, (i\in M)$, where $(\cdot, u)$ is any feasible point of $H$.
Then, $\bar{x}$ is an optimal solution to (HOP) if and only if $(\bar{x}, 1-\alpha)$ is an optimal solution to $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$. Both problems have the same optimal values.
Proof If $\bar{x}$ is an optimal point of (HOP), then $(\bar{x}, 1-\alpha)$ is a feasible point of $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$. Thus
Next we show that $ \min\limits_{x\in K}f(x)=\min\limits_{(x, u)\in H}F_{\alpha}(x, u)$, on the contrary, if
then there is a minimizing sequence $\big\{(y_{n}, u_{n})\big\}\in H$, such that
Therefore, for $n$ sufficiently large, say $n\geqslant n_{0}$,
But, let $x_{n}=(u_{n}+\alpha)^{\frac{1}{p}}y_{n}\in \Omega, $ then, by $(4.12)$ and $\big\{(y_{n}, u_{n})\big\}\in H$, we have
that is, $x_{n}\in K$ and
when $n$ is sufficiently large. This contradicts the fact that $\bar{x}$ is an optimal solution of (HOP). Hence, $ \min\limits_{x\in K}f(x)=\min\limits_{(x, u)\in H}F_{\alpha}(x, u).$
Conversely, let $(\bar{x}, 1-\alpha)$ be an optimal solution to $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$. We now show that $\bar{x}$ must be an optimal solution of (HOP).
Let $\bar{y}=(\bar{u}+\alpha)^{\frac{1}{p}}\bar{x}.$ We note that $\bar{y}$ is a feasible point of (HOP). Indeed, by the homogeneity of the function $g_{i}\, (i\in M)$ and (4.12), we know
Hence
It follows from (4.13), (4.14) that
then, $\bar{u}=1-\alpha$, and $\bar{y}=(\bar{u}+\alpha)^{\frac{1}{p}}\bar{x}=\bar{x}$ is an optimal point of (HOP).
Remark4.2 It is not difficult to verify that the inequality $(4.12)$ holds trivially if one of the following holds:
(ⅰ) $p\leqslant q_{i}, \, \, i\in M$;
(ⅱ) $u+\alpha=1$.
That is, our results is an extension of that in [1, Theorem 4.4].
Now we present two examples of nonsmooth homogeneous optimization problem to illustrate the effectiveness of the results in Theorem 4.1 and 4.2.
Example 4.1
where $f(x)=|x|$ is absolutely 1-homogeneous, $g(x)= \max\{0, x\}$ is positively 1-homogeneous, $b=b_{1}=0$, $\Omega=(-\infty, +\infty)$ is a closed cone of $R$.
Let $\alpha=\frac{1}{2}$, and the embedding problem of (HOP) is presented as follows:
(ⅰ) $0\in\partial f(0)=[-1, 1]$, $0\in\partial g(0)=[0, 1]$, take $\lambda_{1}=1$, then
and $1\cdot g(0)=0, $ i.e., 0 is a KKT point of (HOP).
Now we show that $(0, \frac{1}{2})$ is a KKT point of $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$ with associated L-KKT multiplier (1, 0). In fact, $0\in\partial f(0)+\partial g(0)=(\frac{1}{2}+\frac{1}{2})\big[\partial f(0)+1\cdot\partial g(0)\big]$ is obvious and (4.2)-(4.4) hold trivially.
(ⅱ) Conversely, it is easy to check $(0, \frac{1}{2})$ is a KKT point of $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$ with associated L-KKT multiplier (1, 0), and $\bar{u}=1-\frac{1}{2}=\frac{1}{2}$, $\bar{\mu}=0$, $\bar{x}=0$ is a KKT point of (HOP) with associated L-KKT multiplier $\bar{\lambda}=1$.
Furthermore, graphically, we can see that 0 is an optimal solution of (HOP) if and only if $(0, \frac{1}{2})$ is an optimal solution of $\mathrm{\widehat{(HOP)}}$.
Example 4.2
where $f:R^{2}\rightarrow R$, $f(x)=\|x\|$ is absolutely 1-homogeneous, $g(x)=x_{1}^{2}+x_{2}^{2}$ is positively $2$-homogeneous, $\Omega=\big\{(x_{1}, x_{2}):x_{2}\geqslant|x_{1}|\big\}$ is a closed cone of $R^{2}$.
Let $\alpha=\frac{1}{2}$, then the embedding problem of (HOP) is presented as follows:
(ⅰ) $\partial f(0, 0)=\{\zeta\in R^{2}:\zeta_{i}\in[-1, 1], \, \, i=1, 2\}$, $\partial g(0, 0)=\{(0, 0)\}$. Take $\bar{\lambda}=1$, it follows that $(0, 0)\in\partial f(0, 0)+1\cdot\partial g(0, 0)$ and $1\cdot\big(g(0, 0)-0\big)=0$, i.e., (0, 0) is a KKT point of (HOP). Now we show that $\big((0, 0), \frac{1}{2}\big)$ is a KKT point of $\mathrm{\widehat{(HOP)}}$ with associated L-KKT multiplier (1, 0). In fact, $(0, 0)\in\partial f(0, 0)+1\cdot\partial g(0, 0)=(\frac{1}{2}+\frac{1}{2})\big[\partial f(0, 0)+1\cdot\partial g(0, 0)\big]$ is obvious and (4.2)-(4.4) hold trivially.
(ⅱ) Conversely, it is easy to verify that $\big((0, 0), \frac{1}{2}\big)$ is a KKT of $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$ with associated L-KKT multiplier (1, 0). And $\bar{u}=1-\frac{1}{2}=\frac{1}{2}$, $\bar{\mu}=0$, then $\bar{x}=(0, 0)$ is a KKT of (HOP) with associated L-KKT multiplier $\bar{\lambda}=1$.
Furthermore, graphically, we can see that (0, 0) is an optimal solution of (HOP) if and only if $\big((0, 0), \frac{1}{2}\big)$ is an optimal solution of $\mathrm{\widehat{(HOP)}}$.
Remark4.3 So, and first, the above two examples verify that even when $p\neq q_{i}\, (i\in M)$, $f$ and $g_{i}\, (i\in M)$ involved are nonsmooth, the one-to-one correspondence of KKT points (optimal solutions) of (HOP) and $(\mathrm{\widehat{HOP}})$ is still true, that is, our results is a true extension of those in [1, 2].For more details of the duality problems, see [12, 13] and references therein.